ImageVerifierCode 换一换
格式:PDF , 页数:45 ,大小:473.57KB ,
资源ID:4403527      下载积分:25 金币
验证码下载
登录下载
邮箱/手机:
验证码: 获取验证码
温馨提示:
支付成功后,系统会自动生成账号(用户名为邮箱或者手机号,密码是验证码),方便下次登录下载和查询订单;
特别说明:
请自助下载,系统不会自动发送文件的哦; 如果您已付费,想二次下载,请登录后访问:我的下载记录
支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
验证码:   换一换

开通VIP
 

温馨提示:由于个人手机设置不同,如果发现不能下载,请复制以下地址【https://www.zixin.com.cn/docdown/4403527.html】到电脑端继续下载(重复下载【60天内】不扣币)。

已注册用户请登录:
账号:
密码:
验证码:   换一换
  忘记密码?
三方登录: 微信登录   QQ登录  
声明  |  会员权益     获赠5币     写作写作

1、填表:    下载求助     留言反馈    退款申请
2、咨信平台为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,收益归上传人(含作者)所有;本站仅是提供信息存储空间和展示预览,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容不做任何修改或编辑。所展示的作品文档包括内容和图片全部来源于网络用户和作者上传投稿,我们不确定上传用户享有完全著作权,根据《信息网络传播权保护条例》,如果侵犯了您的版权、权益或隐私,请联系我们,核实后会尽快下架及时删除,并可随时和客服了解处理情况,尊重保护知识产权我们共同努力。
3、文档的总页数、文档格式和文档大小以系统显示为准(内容中显示的页数不一定正确),网站客服只以系统显示的页数、文件格式、文档大小作为仲裁依据,个别因单元格分列造成显示页码不一将协商解决,平台无法对文档的真实性、完整性、权威性、准确性、专业性及其观点立场做任何保证或承诺,下载前须认真查看,确认无误后再购买,务必慎重购买;若有违法违纪将进行移交司法处理,若涉侵权平台将进行基本处罚并下架。
4、本站所有内容均由用户上传,付费前请自行鉴别,如您付费,意味着您已接受本站规则且自行承担风险,本站不进行额外附加服务,虚拟产品一经售出概不退款(未进行购买下载可退充值款),文档一经付费(服务费)、不意味着购买了该文档的版权,仅供个人/单位学习、研究之用,不得用于商业用途,未经授权,严禁复制、发行、汇编、翻译或者网络传播等,侵权必究。
5、如你看到网页展示的文档有www.zixin.com.cn水印,是因预览和防盗链等技术需要对页面进行转换压缩成图而已,我们并不对上传的文档进行任何编辑或修改,文档下载后都不会有水印标识(原文档上传前个别存留的除外),下载后原文更清晰;试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓;PPT和DOC文档可被视为“模板”,允许上传人保留章节、目录结构的情况下删减部份的内容;PDF文档不管是原文档转换或图片扫描而得,本站不作要求视为允许,下载前自行私信或留言给上传者【宇***】。
6、本文档所展示的图片、画像、字体、音乐的版权可能需版权方额外授权,请谨慎使用;网站提供的党政主题相关内容(国旗、国徽、党徽--等)目的在于配合国家政策宣传,仅限个人学习分享使用,禁止用于任何广告和商用目的。
7、本文档遇到问题,请及时私信或留言给本站上传会员【宇***】,需本站解决可联系【 微信客服】、【 QQ客服】,若有其他问题请点击或扫码反馈【 服务填表】;文档侵犯商业秘密、侵犯著作权、侵犯人身权等,请点击“【 版权申诉】”(推荐),意见反馈和侵权处理邮箱:1219186828@qq.com;也可以拔打客服电话:4008-655-100;投诉/维权电话:4009-655-100。

注意事项

本文(2024年超边际借款人与货币政策的抵押贷款支付渠道(英).pdf)为本站上传会员【宇***】主动上传,咨信网仅是提供信息存储空间和展示预览,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知咨信网(发送邮件至1219186828@qq.com、拔打电话4008-655-100或【 微信客服】、【 QQ客服】),核实后会尽快下架及时删除,并可随时和客服了解处理情况,尊重保护知识产权我们共同努力。
温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载【60天内】不扣币。 服务填表

2024年超边际借款人与货币政策的抵押贷款支付渠道(英).pdf

1、Finance and Economics Discussion SeriesFederal Reserve Board,Washington,D.C.ISSN 1936-2854(Print)ISSN 2767-3898(Online)Inframarginal Borrowers and the Mortgage Payment Channel ofMonetary PolicyDaniel Ringo2024-069Please cite this paper as:Ringo,Daniel(2024).“Inframarginal Borrowers and the Mortgage

2、Payment Channel ofMonetary Policy,”Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2024-069.Washington:Boardof Governors of the Federal Reserve System,https:/doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2024.069.NOTE:Staffworking papers in the Finance and Economics Discussion Series(FEDS)are preliminarymaterials circulated to sti

3、mulate discussion and critical comment.The analysis and conclusions set forthare those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staffor theBoard of Governors.References in publications to the Finance and Economics Discussion Series(other thanacknowledgement)sho

4、uld be cleared with the author(s)to protect the tentative character of these papers.Inframarginal Borrowers and the Mortgage PaymentChannel of Monetary PolicyDaniel RingoFederal Reserve BoardJuly 30,2024AbstractDespite the widespread use of fixed-rate mortgages in the United States,I show that monet

5、arypolicy is effectively passed through to aggregate outstanding mortgage debt service.Using creditbureau,lender,and servicer data on mortgage payments and originations and exogenous mone-tary policy shocks,I estimate a mortgage rate semi-elasticity of payments over 10.Inframarginalborrowershousehol

6、ds whose choice to buy a home or refinance does not depend on the partic-ular monetary policy decision under considerationare the most important conduit,explainingover half of the pass-through.Consistently large flows of inframarginal borrowing relative to thestock of outstanding debt account for th

7、e strength of this channel.Households with adjustable-ratemortgages and marginal refinancers,the focus of much of the literature on monetary policys effecton mortgage borrowers,each explain about 20 percent of the pass-through.I show the mortgagepayment channel induces a lag in the operation of poli

8、cy,as the cumulative effects on debt servicebuild over time in response to persistent shocks to longer-term rates.Estimated magnitudes suggestthat mortgage payments are a primary channel by which monetary policy affects consumption.Keywords:Monetary policy;interest rates;refinancing channel;debt ser

9、viceJEL codes:G21;E43;E52.MS93,BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystem,WashingtonD.C.20551daniel.r.ringofrb.gov.Thanks to Neil Bhutta,John Driscoll,and seminar participants at the Federal Re-serve Board and Ghent University Empirical Macroeconomics Workshop for helpful comments.The analysisand con

10、clusions set forth are those of the author and do not indicate concurrence by other members of theresearch staffor the Board of Governors.11IntroductionMonetary policy can affect households consumption via their debt service payments,in-creasing their disposable incomes net of required payments as i

11、nterest rates decrease andvice versa.Residential mortgage debt represents the outright majority of all household debtand is the largest source of debt service obligations,and so should be a potent channel bywhich monetary policy can influence consumer demand.In the United States,however,thepopularit

12、y of fixed-rate mortgages presents an obstacle to the pass-through of interest ratechanges to payments.When rates rise,debtor households will hang on to their old rates andbe unaffected.When rates fall,only a fraction of households for whom refinancing would beprofitable exercise their option to do

13、so.The frictions inherent in this process have moti-vated a growing body of literature analyzing the refinancing channel of monetary policy.1Inan international context,it is commonly argued that the prevalance of fixed-rate mortgagesdampens the effectiveness of monetary policy in countries like the

14、U.S.2In this paper,I show that the pass-through of monetary policy shocks to mortgagepayments in the U.S.is actually quite robust due to the large volume of borrowing byinframarginal borrowers.These are households whose decision to take out a new loan doesnot depend on the particular monetary policy

15、 action under consideration,but whose paymentfor that new loan still depends on the stance of policy.Importantly,inframarginal borrowersinclude households who are borrowing for the purposes of home purchase,refinancing,orany other ends.While only a small percentage of households engage in any new mo

16、rtgageborrowing in a given year,in dollar terms annual new borrowing represents approximatelyone quarter of the outstanding stock of household mortgage debt.This is because newloans tend to be larger than the unpaid principal balance of existing loans,and explains thestrength of the mortgage payment

17、 channel.Historically,a large percentage of mortgage debthas carried a recently determined interest rate.The effect of a typical monetary policy shock on the monthly payments of an infra-marginal borrower is small relative to that experienced by a marginal refinancera household1See Amromin,Bhutta an

18、d Keys(2020)for a helpful summary.2See,e.g.,Bernanke(2007),Calza,Monacelli and Stracca(2013),Rubio(2011),or Kim and Lim(2020).2that would be induced into or out of refinancing their current mortgage by a small changein rates.However,inframarginal borrowers are so much more numerous than marginal bor

19、-rowers that the inframarginal channel is more than twice as important for the pass-throughof rate shocks to aggregate payments.I find that over the last 25 years,a monetary pol-icy shock which cuts mortgage rates by only 7 basis points would reduce aggregate annualmortgage payments by approximately

20、$9 billion in 2023 dollars.Inframarginal borrowerswould account for about$5 billion of this reduction,and marginal refinancers$2 billion.An additional$2 billion would go to the minority of borrowers with adjustable-rate mort-gages(ARMs),although this latter channel has diminished in recent years.Mar

21、ginal homepurchase borrowers and the intensive margin of borrowing(i.e.,the amount borrowed con-ditional on getting a loan)are not significant channels of pass-through to payments in thefirst few years post-shock.The stance of monetary policy and the level of mortgage rates are endogenous to the sta

22、teof the economy.To consistently estimate the effects of policy decisions,I therefore exploitvariation from the exogenous,unanticipated components of rate responses to Federal OpenMarket Committee(FOMC)announcements.I begin by estimating the effects of monetarypolicy shocks on mortgage interest rate

23、s.It is important here to recognize that mortgageinterest rates are tied to yields on relatively longer-maturity debt(as a typical mortgagewill endure for years before prepaying)and the Federal Reserve has tools at its disposalthat affect different portions of the yield curve differently.The Fed can

24、 directly control veryshort-term rates by setting the overnight federal funds rate.Longer-term rates depend moreon investors beliefs about the future path of monetary policy decisions,and the Fed canattempt to influence these beliefs via forward guidance and asset purchases.I therefore usethe series

25、 of monetary policy shocks estimated by Swanson(2021),who separately identifiedshocks to the federal funds rate,forward guidance,and large-scale asset purchases(LSAP)contained in FOMC announcements.3Using the local projections estimator of Jord a(2005),3Lewis(2023)also estimates shock series that di

26、sentangle these components using different identifyingassumptions than Swanson(2021).In addition,Lewis(2023)attempts to isolate a fourth component,theFed information effect.In Appendix Section A.1 I show my results are robust to using these alternativeshocks series.3I estimate that a one standard de

27、viation forward guidance shock raises mortgage rates byan average of 7.4 basis points over the three years post-shock.4Shocks to the federal fundsrate do not show any demonstrable effect on mortgage rates,however.The LSAP shock isestimated to have a strong initial effect on mortgage rates,but this q

28、uickly fades.Next,I estimate how the average payments of mortgage borrowers are affected by mon-etary policy shocks empirically.I construct a time series of the average mortgage paymentsof all outstanding mortgage borrowers using nationally representative credit bureau datafrom 1999 through 2023.Aga

29、in using the local projections estimator,I estimate that a onestandard deviation forward guidance shock increased the average payments of borrowers by0.89 percent after three years,or approximately$9 billion per year.Putting the estimates to-gether,each basis point increase in mortgage rates is esti

30、mated to increase annual paymentsby over$1 billion;in other words,the interest rate semi-elasticity of mortgage payments isabout 10.The estimated effects on mortgage debt service are large enough to explain much of theconsumption response to monetary policy shocks.Cloyne,Ferreira and Surico(2020)est

31、i-mate that in the U.S.a 25 basis point generic monetary policy shock would decrease durableand non-durable consumption by approximately 0.9 and 0.15 percent,respectively,threeyears post-shock.With receent annual personal consumption expenditures of approximately$2 trillion and$17 trillion in these

32、categories,this implies a total reduction of about$45billion per year.My estimates suggest that a 25 basis point shock to mortgage rates wouldincrease annual mortgage payments by about$30 billion by year three.If the marginalpropensity to consume out of a persistent change in disposable income is hi

33、gh,most of theeffect of monetary policy on consumption can therefore be explained by the direct effect of themortgage payment channel.5Any multiplier effects from the shock to mortgage borrowers4Prior studies,such as Hamilton(2008),Gorea,Kryvtsov and Kudlyak(2022),and Ringo(2024),haveshown the effec

34、t of forward guidance on mortgage rates in the short-term,but this study is the first I amaware of to demonstrate that the effect persists for years.5While estimates of the marginal propensity to consume vary in the literature,most researchers findthat it is high for permanent shocks to income.See J

35、appelli and Pistaferri(2010)for a review of theliterature.Changes in mortgage payments represent a transfer between borrowers and creditors,so thereare potentially offsetting consumption effects.However,most mortgage debt in the US(often packaged intomortgage backed securities)is held by commercial

36、banks,the Federal Reserve,or institutional investors,allof whom presumably have a low marginal propensity to consume.4consumption would further increase the importance of the mortgage payment channel.Thestrength of the mortgage payment channel also provides an explanation for monetary pol-icys effec

37、t on consumption despite micro evidence suggesting a low intertemporal elasticityof substitution(see,e.g.,Best et al.,2020).The total estimated change in payments includes the effects on inframarginal borrowers,marginal borrowers,and existing ARMs(whose mortgagors do not need to engage in anynew ori

38、ginations to be affected).Additionally,households engaging in new borrowing mayoffset some of the effect of monetary policy on payments by making an intensive marginadjustment,i.e.reducing the size of their loans in the face of higher rates.To identify therelative importance of these channels,I esti

39、mate their magnitudes separately.Inframarginal borrowers are simple to model because,by definition,their borrowing deci-sions are exogenous to the rate shock.The magnitude of the inframarginal borrower channelcan therefore be straightforwardly estimated via a simple back-of-the-envelope calculation.

40、Using the average origination volume and mortgage interest rate over the past 25 years,Icalculate that cutting rates by 7.4 basis points for three years should reduce aggregate mort-gage debt service by approximately$5.2 billion per annum.The effect builds linearly overtime so long as the lower rate

41、 is maintained,as each month a new cohort of inframarginalborrowers are affected while cohorts that previously got their loan continue to pay the lowerrate.Comparing this simple calculation to the total estimated change in payments,it seemsthat inframarginal borrowers are reponsible for just over ha

42、lf of the pass-through of monetarypolicy.In addition to the increased or decreased payments faced by these inframarginal borrow-ers,a rate shock can pull in or exclude marginal borrowers.The number of such borrowerscan be estimated by the responsiveness of origination volumes to rate shocksthe diffe

43、r-ence between this estimated number and the total number of originations is the numberof inframarginal borrowers.Marginal borrowers are vastly outnumbered by inframarginalborrowers for rate shocks of a typical historical magnitude,but the effect on their paymentsper-borrower may be much larger.This

44、 is because,for marginal borrowers,the counterfactualpayment is their current existing payment(with its old rate potentially very different from5current rates),not the payment they would get originating the same loan with a marginallydifferent rate(as it would be for inframarginal borrowers).6To det

45、ermine the magnitude of the marginal refinance channel,I estimate the effect of thesame monetary policy shock on the number of weekly refinance originations over the 1999-2023 period.Again using a local projections estimator,I find the shock decreases refinancingvolumes by 3.5 percent over the three

46、 years post-shock,suggesting approximately$2 billionof the total increase in payments comes from marginal refinancers.For the marginal homepurchase channel,I run the same estimator on the number of weekly home purchase origi-nations.I do not find effects on home purchase lending volumes that are eit

47、her statisticallysignificant or economically consequential for average payment amounts.To determine the magnitude of the ARM channel,I use a monthly panel of servicingrecords of individual ARMs from 2000 through 2023.The local projections estimator indi-cates that the same monetary policy shock incr

48、eases ARM payments by approximately 1.2percent,equivalent to$2 billion in additional payments per year.The back-of-the-envelope calculation of the inframarginal borrower channel ignores thepossibility that households adjust on other margins(i.e.,loan size).To test this implicitassumption,I next esti

49、mate the magnitudes of the intensive margin channel.To do so,I run the local projections estimator on a weekly series of the average loan size of neworiginations.I find effects that are close to zero for the first few years after the shock.Theassumption of no intensive-margin adjustment used in the

50、back-of-the-envelope calculationof the inframarginal channel appears benign.Together,the estimated magnitudes of the inframarginal borrower,marginal refinancer,and ARM channels add up to be close to the estimated net effect on aggregate payments.The estimates of channel-specific magnitudes use outco

移动网页_全站_页脚广告1

关于我们      便捷服务       自信AI       AI导航        获赠5币

©2010-2024 宁波自信网络信息技术有限公司  版权所有

客服电话:4008-655-100  投诉/维权电话:4009-655-100

gongan.png浙公网安备33021202000488号   

icp.png浙ICP备2021020529号-1  |  浙B2-20240490  

关注我们 :gzh.png    weibo.png    LOFTER.png 

客服